
Poverty Statistics:
The Issues Simon Schwartzman
Brazilian Institute for Geography and Statistics
prepared as background text for the UN Statistical
Commission's Expert Group on Poverty
Statistics, 1998
1. The renewed interest in poverty statistics
2. Absolute and relative poverty
3. Types of poverty
4. The uses of poverty statistics
Notes
1. The renewed
interest in poverty statistics.
Poverty has been a constant presence in man's history, but its meaning has
changed through time(1). Most people in traditional
societies were poor, and this was accepted as natural and unavoidable. The
current understanding, today, is that the condition of poverty is unacceptable,
and that it should be possible to find the ways to eradicate it. Many reasons
have been presented for this change of views, of which three seem to be
more salient. The first is ethnical and moral: the notion that all human
beings are equal, and should be entitled not only to civil and political
rights, but also to social rights such as food, shelter, education and personal
security. This notion has been gathering increased support for two centuries
or more, and is becoming still more intense as the plight of socially deprived
populations are exposed daily to whoever has access to a TV set or a radio.
The second is more practical and less altruistic: poverty, particularly
when associated with war and economic disorder, leads to social unrest,
reduces the values of salaries and goods, leads to national and international
migration, and threatens the life styles of those who are better off.
The third is more conceptual. In the past, industrialization, the development
of science and technology and the spreading of education led to general
belief that the problems of poverty, ignorance and deprivation were about
to disappear, either through the expansion of private entrepreneurship or
through the purposeful and rational action of governments and international
organizations, or some combination of them. Malthus' pessimism was obfuscated
by the image of "unbounded Prometheus", an endless expansion of
wealth and well-being; this image was prevalent both in capitalist and in
socialist countries, and adopted by the developing countries in the Southern
Hemisphere in their drive for political independence and socioeconomic development.
According to this view, if you did not work, but wanted to, you were not
poor, but unemployed. Economic fluctuations created unemployment, and the
1929 crisis produced millions of unemployed in the United States and Europe.
Different from poverty, unemployment was understood to be a by-product of
modern industrial economy, and mechanisms had to be devised to reduce it,
or compensate for its consequences. Everybody, in principle, should have
a stable work in a modern economy, and action was needed when it did not
happen. Anti-cyclic policies, on one hand, and unemployment compensation,
on the other, were landmarks of the post 1929, Welfare State capitalism.
Unemployment had to be measured, and proper statistics should be devised
for that, but it should not be confounded with poverty. To be unemployed
was an attribute of industrial workers, not of people outside the productive
system - housewives, old people, beggars, the lumpenproletariat.
The current standard statistical definition of unemployment, adopted and
implemented by the International Labor Organization, measures precisely
that. Unemployed are those who are without jobs, but are actively looking
for one, or living from unemployment benefits. If you are not looking for
a job, if you live from welfare, if you live from handouts from your family,
if you beg in the streets, you are not unemployed, but simply outside the
economically active population. Unemployment statistics became an excellent
instrument for measuring the short-term fluctuations of economic activity
and to devise policies for unemployment compensations and safety nets, and
the widespread use of similar methodologies allowed for meaningful international
comparisons.
The assumption that economic development by itself would provide everybody
with an adequate job, however, is now being questioned in industrialized
countries, and never really existed in developing and underdeveloped societies(2),
where most of the population remained and still remain outside the mainstream
of production and access to essential goods and services. The growing awareness
and concern with the problems of poverty, expressed in recent years in several
summit conferences and the growing presence of the poverty issue in the
agenda of national governments and international organizations has led to
a renewed need to measure and understand the realities of poverty in its
different manifestations, as a first step to devise policies to reduce it
or at least to respond to its more dire consequences, and to monitor its
course.
2. Absolute and relative poverty
What is poverty? who defines it? to what extent is the development of regular
systems of poverty statistics influenced by the agendas of governments,
political and religious groups and associations? how does the existence
of such data affect public opinion and policies? Like all major statistical
constructs, the definition of poverty and associated measurements are not
just a technical matter, but are shaped by a confluence of social concerns,
governmental demands, the contributions of researchers in economics and
the social sciences, and the technical expertise of professional statisticians.
Two very broad concepts of poverty are being utilized today by statistical
agencies and researchers throughout the world, responding to different concerns.
One is the concept of absolute poverty, understood as the minimum
set of resources a person needs to survive. The other is the concept of
relative poverty, a measurement of the resources and living conditions
of parts of the population in relation to others. Absolute poverty is a
matter of acute deprivation, hunger, premature death and suffering; in practice,
it may be difficult to measure it in a consistent way, but the consensual
understanding is that this is an intolerable situation, requiring prompt
corrective action. The measurement of relative poverty, on the other hand,
is more a matter of social equity, and is associated with the development
of policies for the reduction of social inequalities and the creation of
mechanisms to compensate for the more extreme differences in wealth, living
conditions and opportunities. The measurement of absolute poverty is typical
of less developed countries in Latin America, Africa and Asia, while the
measurement of relative poverty is more typical of highly industrialized
and developed countries, such as the United States, Canada and Australia.
These two, very broad definitions of poverty have led to different approaches
in the measurement of poverty which are being adopted by statistical offices
throughout the world. The dominant practice is to measure the poverty levels
of households or dwellings. Absolute poverty can be measured, in principle,
in terms of the basic needs a person has to meet in order to survive
adequately in modern society. Depending on the availability of data, the
satisfaction of basic needs can be measured directly, through anthropometric
and medical measurements of the physical conditions of the population; or
indirectly, through the study of the population consumption patterns or
income levels. Ideally, the three kinds of information should be used.
The use of the expressions "adequately" and "modern society"
show that it is very difficult, if not impossible, to define "absolute
poverty" objectively, without introducing value judgements and elements
of comparison. One approach used by several countries is to estimate the
minimum intake of calories and proteins a person needs in order to survive,
and use this measurement as a yardstick for the measurement of absolute
poverty. There is a long list of technical problems with this approach:
the biological definition of this "minimum"; its variation according
to the age, sex, season, climate, physical built and type of activity of
each person; the equivalences among different types and quantities of food
and nutrients; the problems associated with food imbalances; and the need
to add a few other essential non-food needs, such as shelter and clothing,
with similar problems of variance and equivalences. "Adequate"
survival in modern societies, of course, require more than sheer physical
survival: it should include, among other things, resources for health maintenance
and medical care, transportation, education, access to information and socially
accepted clothing and living conditions. As we introduce these other elements,
the notion of what is the "minimum" becomes a matter of values,
preferences and comparisons - and absolute measurements turn into relative
measurements.
The measurement of absolute poverty faces a set of typical problems. The
first is the need to convert the ingredients which enter in the minimum
basket of essential goods and services, regardless of their definition,
into a common denominator, usually a monetary value. This can be a daunting
task, given the seasonal, regional and cultural differences in consumption
patterns and prices. To do this, it is necessary to have data from consumption
patterns, household budgets and prices, often provided by independent surveys.
Comparisons among regions and through time require adjustments and compensations
for inflation and changes in quality of consumed goods, and the construction
of parity standards of purchasing power. The second problem is to account
for non-monetary income and benefits, derived from production for self-consumption,
personal services and transfers among members of the extended family, and
benefits provided by the government or the community. The very concepts
of a "household", "family" or "dwelling" are
subject to significant cultural, local and historical variations, and require
careful analysis. It is also important to take into account the existence
of assets, in relation to current monetary and non monetary income The poorer
and less capitalized a society or a community, the larger is their reliance
on non-monetary resources of all kinds, and the harder it is to translate
these resources into meaningful prices. Proper procedures to measure or
estimate these non-monetary resources are an essential element in all attempts
to measure poverty.
The final result of this process is the identification of one or several
thresholds of poverty, and the assignation of quantities of people to these
values. In some cases it is deemed necessary to identify values for poverty
and for indigence, the latter referring to persons or dwellings which are
below the minimum subsistence level. It is also possible to measure the
poverty gap - how far away a given population is from the defined minimum,
either from above or from below. Because of the large number of assumptions
implied in all steps of this complex process of statistical processing,
the numbers produced at the end are to some extent arbitrary, and should
be carefully checked against other available information and common sense
and other social expectations.
The discretionary nature of poverty figures is much clearer when the goal
is to measure relative, not absolute poverty. Different and more or less
arbitrary poverty thresholds can be defined - persons earning below a given
percentage of the national or regional income, or placed at a given distance
below the national average, or having access to a given basket of goods
and services.
3. Types of poverty
The measurement of poverty is just a first approximation to the problems
of social and economic deprivation. Poverty can be caused by different factors
and conditions, and assume very different nature and characteristics. Very
often the interest of policy makers is to identify groups and regions which
are particularly affected by deprivation, so that they can receive the benefits
of public action - vulnerable groups such as children, the elderly, women,
racial, ethnic and linguistic minorities. If the intention is not just to
identify those in need, but to understand better the reasons for their predicament,
it is necessary to examine the possible determinants of this condition.
Rural poverty in traditional economies is very different from urban poverty
in large metropolitan areas, and require very different policies. Different
determinants and correlates of poverty can be measured and sorted out by
statistical means - poverty associated with demographic conditions, such
as family size; created by unemployment; caused by poor quality jobs; by
lack of education; by social discrimination; by lack of "social capital",
such as family and community organizations and networks; by economic changes,
climate changes, natural catastrophes, and war.
The procedures used for the measurement of poverty can be very complex,
and require data sets that are more frequently found in rich countries,
where the problems of poverty are less severe, than in poorer ones, where
they are more significant. Depending on the objectives, the following statistical
instruments have been used by different countries in these measurements:
- surveys on eating habits of the population, the nutritional contents
of different types of food and their relation with health indicators.
This kind of study is not usually part of the work of statistical offices,
but is essential for the measurement of basic needs
- surveys on family and dwelling budgets. These surveys are carried
on by statistical offices with some regularity, in order to ascertain
the consumption baskets of different social groups, to be used in the
calculation of cost of living indexes. They provide information on the
resources going to the acquisition of essential goods (food, housing,
shelter), and eventually on the access of the population to non-monetary
services and money transfers.
- household surveys - Most countries carry periodical household surveys
every year or a lower intervals, covering aspects such as housing conditions,
labor, employment, education, income and other subjects. These surveys
are more detailed and broader than the continuous employment and consumer
price surveys, and large enough to represent major groups and regions
in a country. Household surveys are the basic instrument to follow the
conditions of the population in terms of living conditions, income and
employment. They have, however, some limitations: they are usually not
representative of small regions or population groups; they may be not
be frequent enough; and they should be combined with information on
family budgets, expenditures and prices.
- continuous employment and price surveys. These are usually well targeted,
monthly surveys designed to follow the short-term fluctuations of employment
and prices, and, when combined with information from other surveys,
can provide also information on the fluctuation of the poverty conditions
of the population.
- living standards surveys - this methodology, applied in several countries
with the support of the World Bank, consists in very extensive questionnaires
applied to relatively small samples of households. The attempt is to
combine in the same survey all main dimensions related to living conditions,
specially of the poor: consumption patterns, household budgets, anthropometric
indicators, income, non-monetary benefits and transfers, and so forth.
This type of survey seems to be of special interest for in-depth analysis
of the conditions of poverty and their correlates. Because of the small
samples, however, and the complexity of the questionnaire, they seem
to be less useful for the establishment of parameters, standards and
poverty thresholds for large regions and countries.
- census data - Census information is essential when there is the need
to measure poverty at the local level. Two difficulties, however, are
apparent. The first is the long period, typically ten years, between
censuses; the second is the limited number of variables in census questionnaires.
Income is usually under reported in census data, and there is no or
little information on non-monetary transfers. There are many ways, however,
to combine and calibrate the census information through the use of household
surveys of different kinds, as a way to overcome their limitations.
- administrative registers - when governments deliver benefits associated
with poverty conditions, they can develop administrative records which
inform, by definition, the number and other characteristics of the population
considered poor. This information should be combined with data derived
from household surveys and similar sources, so that the it may be possible
to gauge the actual coverage of these benefits.
In short, there is a large array of instruments used in the measurement
of poverty, and it is the responsibility of statistical offices to identify
those that are more adequate to their specific purposes, and practical in
terms of their financial resources and technical and administrative skills.
4. The uses of poverty statistics
The definitions of poverty and the selection of statistical instruments
depend on the intended use of the results. Three main uses can be identified
in the current international practice:
- the establishment of poverty lines. The goal, here, is to identify
a threshold of income or need satisfaction dividing what is acceptable
and what is not acceptable in a given society. Once defined, poverty
lines can be used to distribute benefits of different kinds, either
in cash or in services; to identify groups or regions requiring special
policies for poverty reduction; and to monitor the progress of such
programs through time. Once established by official statistical institutions
or governmental agencies, poverty lines create expectations and lead
to the allocation of public funds to specific programs, and are therefore
very difficult to change. Whether a country decides or not to adopt
an official poverty line is a matter of national policy. From the statistical
point of view, the best practice to this work seem to be the use of
methodologies which can be simple to understand in their procedures
and implications, and with built-in mechanisms for adjustment according
to changes in prices, consumption habits of the population and national
wealth.
- international comparisons. International organizations have a natural
interest in comparing countries according to their poverty levels. This
information is very useful to identify countries in need of international
assistance, to monitor and to evaluate the effects of policies of social
and economic development in terms of their actual effects on the most
needed groups. The technical problems associated with international
comparisons, however, are very significant, given the highly divergent
approaches of different countries in the establishment of their poverty
measurements, and the need to establish equivalences among countries
in terms of the consumption patterns and purchasing power of their currency
for the poor population. One way of reducing this problem is for countries
to adopt the same methodology for the development of their poverty statistics,
and several international organizations are working in this direction,
by providing technical assistance to countries interested in the development
of these measurements, or by sponsoring activities geared to the comparison
of experiences and the adoption of comparable methodologies by groups
of countries. This is a slow process at best, and still leave open the
problems of international parities and conversions. Another approach
is to adopt very simple and arbitrary measurement of poverty (the "one
dollar per person per day" used by the World Bank) for rough estimates
and overviews, under the assumption that they would not be much worse
than what could come out from very elaborated procedures and calculations.
- The identification of poverty syndromes and their correlates. The
goal, here, is not just the measurement of poverty levels, but the understanding
of the main characteristics of the poor groups, with the understanding
that different kinds of poverty require different policies for poverty
reduction. The kind of statistics needed for this approach is different
from the uses used for the establishment of poverty levels: they should
include a broad set of socioeconomic variables and be amenable to complex
econometric analysis, which are more important than the definition of
poverty thresholds. At best, they should also allow for the follow-up
of poverty-stricken groups through time, with the use of panel surveys.
These objectives are not incompatible, and statistical agencies can and
often do engage in all of them, making use of a wide array of methodologies
and approaches, responding differently to the demands of different constituencies.
A recommendation about the best practices in poverty statistics should not
stress the superiority of one among the other goals. What is necessary is
to have a clear notion what will be the use of the statistics being developed;
to adjust the methodology for their production, making use of the available
experience; and to be very explicit about the means by which specific results
are being attained.
Notes:
1. For an overview, see Castel, Robert, Le métamorphoses
de la question sociale - une chronique du salariat, Paris, Fayard, 1995.
2. "Marginalidad" was a central issue in Latin
American social sciences in the late sixties and seventies, but did not
seem to have penetrated the regions' statistical offices at the time. Some
references include Acedo Mendoza, Carlos, América Latina, Marginalidad
y subdesarrollo, Caracas: Fondo Editorial Común, 1974; Germani, Gino,
El concepto de marginalidad: significado, raíces históricas y cuestiones
teóricas, con particular referencia a la marginalidad urbana, Buenos
Aires: Ediciones Nueva Visión, c1973; DESAL, Marginalidad en América
Latina; un ensayo de diagnóstico. Santiago, DESAL, 1969 [c1967]; Margulis,
Mario, Migración y marginalidad en la sociedad argentina, Buenos
Aires, Paidós, 1968; Mattelart, Armand. [y] Manuel A. Garretón, Integración
nacional y marginalidad: un ensayo de regionalización social de Chile, Santiago
de Chile, Editorial del Pacifico, 1965; Nún, José, Miguel Murmis [y] Juan
Carlos Marín, La marginalidad en América Latina; informe preliminar,
Buenos Aires: Instituto Torcuato di Tella, Centro de Investigaciones Sociales,
1968; Quijano, Aníbal, Imperialismo y "marginalidad" en América
Latina, Lima: Mosca Azul Editores, 1977; United Nations. Economic Commission
for Latin América, Bibliografía sobre marginalidad social, Santiago
de Chile, La Biblioteca, 1973; Vekemans, Roger, Ismael Silva [y] Jorge Giusti,
La marginalidad en América Latina: un ensayo de conceptualización,
Santiago de Chile, Centro para el Desarrollo Económico y Social de América
latina (DESAL), 1970; Yalour de Tobar, Margot Romano, María Magdalena Chirico
[y] Edith Soubie, Clase obrera, anomia y cambio social. El proceso de
socialización urbana, Buenos Aires: Instituto Torcuato di Tella, 1967.
<