
"Rationalization"
of Higher Education in Latin America Simon Schwartzman
Paper presented to the meeting of the Task Force
on Higher Education, Latin American Studies Association, Los Angeles, September,
1992.
Latin American higher education institutions are known for their sluggishness,
rigidity and inefficient use of resources. A common explanation is that
they lack managerial tradition, and would benefit from efforts to train
their administrative staff and to provide them with the tools of modern
business efficiency. The fact, however, is that several of these institutions
hold the region's best competence in management in their specialized schools,
which educates the executives of their country's more successful private
companies. A slightly more sophisticated explanation is that their inefficiency
derives from their status as public institutions; if they could be privatized,
and ruled according to the requirements of market rationality, their efficiency
would increase. The fact, however, is that some of the best run universities
in Latin America are public, and many of the private ones are known for
their lack of quality and competence. It is clear that the issue of rationality
and rationalization should be discussed on firmer grounds.
Two preliminary and very well known observations should be made on the onset.
Higher education institutions are multi-functional, and cannot be measured
against a common standard (like profit, in the private sector); and then
there is the traditional distinction between "efficiency" and "efficacy".
Private diploma mills are probably very efficient in getting the students
quickly through their educational rituals, but not very efficacious in providing
good training and education.
These two observations set the stage for the discussions of "rationalization":
it is a quest for better use of available resources, and the production
of a basket of non-commensurate products needed by society, in proper quantity
and quality. These products range from professional to general education,
from scientific to technical training, from mass to elite education, from
the transmission of conventional wisdom to the generation of new and controversial
knowledge.
It is not surprising that, when governments and political parties and movements
try to press their country's higher education institutions towards rationalization,
they tend to simplify them, and force them into the Procrustean bed of a
single mode. In the following, we shall review some of these attempts, and
what they entail. We can organize this discussion in terms of three dimensions:
the content of education (research vs. teaching), the control mechanisms
(market vs. state) and the organizational setting (centralization vs. decentralization,
the issue of autonomy). As we look at them, we will be led to take into
account the different groups that participate in the establishment of policy
agenda for higher education in the region, and the experiences of different
countries.
The 1968 higher education reform in Brazil was probably the regions' most
ambitious attempt to bring a country's higher education establishment into
one single dimension of quality and evaluation, that of scientific research.
For the reformers, the research component was the soul of the university,
which would take its lead if freed from the constraints brought about by
the traditional chair system, the divisions among non-academic professional
schools and the presence of multi-disciplinarity in integrated campuses.
The reformers were too naive in their contempt for the strength of the professional
schools, and did not predict the pressure towards mass higher education
which was just getting speed in the country. In the ensuing years, Brazilian
higher education moved further and further away from the "rationality" of
a research-based university model, which remained, however, the only legitimate
pattern which all institutions should strive to emulate.
Chile went through two attempts at rationalization since the military took
power in 1973. At first, the military brought the universities under intervention,
and tried to organize it along a rigid military command structure. There
are many reasons why it did not work, the more obvious being the lack of
legitimacy of the military government and their agents seated in the rectors'
chairs. Less obvious is the fact that, even in the most favorable conditions,
universities are too complex to be handled though mechanisms of vertical
control. The 1980 reform went to the other extreme, and tried to place the
whole university system under market regulation. In practice, they adopted
a mixed system, going from a "core funding" to the public and more traditional
universities to full self-reliance for new institutions. The belief in the
strength of the market made the Chilean authorities more relaxed about the
internal organization of the institutions. A three-tier system was introduced
(full universities, professional institutes and technical training centers),
and deregulation was supposed to open the way for further differentiation.
There seems to be a clear consensus in Chile that some degree of market
competition (whether in the allocation of public resources or in charging
tuition and engaging in contract research) is good for higher education,
but does not work on itself. Someone has to set long-term goals and provide
standards for quality and performance, making sure that the educational
products being sold in the market adhere to some minimal requisites of quality
and competence; someone has to see that higher education continues to produce
the public goods that the market would not buy, but a country cannot dispense
with. This is, roughly, the aim of the reforms being proposed by the new
democratic government: the creation of a National Council of Education,
the development of mechanisms for systematic evaluation of performance,
and procedures of accreditation and reaccreditation for new and old higher
education institutions.
The 1968 Brazilian and the 1980 Chilean reforms share the fact that they
were introduced from the top-down, by authoritarian regimes, and that they
tried to introduce concepts and procedures which were new to the Latin American
experience, namely the centrality of research and the importance of market
regulation. In both cases, these concepts lost their status as the only
answer to the problems of rationalization, but survived the military regimes,
and became important elements in the countries' higher education institutions.
The third dimension, that of autonomy and self-regulation, dates back from
the Cordoba movement of 1918, which became known as the "Reforma Universitaria"
movement, and still reverberates through the Continent. Seen from hindsight,
the Reforma can be seen as an over-politicized movement that worked as a
springboard for the political career of middle-class intellectuals (the
most outstanding example being, perhaps, that of Haya de la Torre and the
Peruvian Acción Popular Revolucionaria - APRA - party), and did not help
to improve de quality and rationality of Latin American higher education
institutions. In fact, the Reforma movement tried to bring to Latin American
universities the centuries-old principle that universities should be self-regulated
institutions, based on the notion that no one except the academics themselves
holds the expertise to tell the universities what to do, and that they should
be free to explore and study whatever their minds dictate, free from outside
interference and authority.
What was missing in the Reforma movement, of course, was that in reality
most Latin American universities were not academic institutions, and the
autonomy conquered by the movement benefitted not so much the academics
but the students, who turned the universities into sanctuaries from where
the governments could be attacked and abused. The 1918 enshrined the principle
of "gobierno tripartito" - a division of power between students, professors
and alumni. No reference was made to the universities' employers, in part
because they did not "belong" to the social group of the educated, but also
because they were so few of them - the universities were part-time teaching
institutions that did not need more than a handful of employees to clean
the buildings and handle the registry of degrees, diplomas and monthly payments
for the professors.
Almost a century later, university autonomy is still an important subject,
but the actors have changed, and the universities are not the same. Between
the twenties and fifties the student movement in the universities were the
breeding grounds for a substantial part of the region's political elites.
After the sixties, the student movement moved further and further to the
left, and in many countries the campuses became the hiding places for urban
guerrillas. In the eighties most of the mobilization of the previous years
withered away, and what remained of the student movement turned into just
another pressure group claiming for free tuition, subsidized restaurants
and public transportation and other minor privileges.
As the student movement faded away, a new actor emerged, the unionized university
teacher. Until the sixties, to teach in a university was an honorary and
prestigious activity for successful professionals, but very seldom a full-time
activity with a corresponding salary. Then, in the public universities in
many countries, thousands of professionals were hired as university teachers,
responding to the expansion of enrollment, very often without the corresponding
academic credentials. In Mexico, in 1970, there were 24 thousand professors
in universities, most of them hired as part time; twenty years later there
were about 100 thousand, a large percentage of which with full salaries,
of whom only 6 thousand could be classified as "highly qualified researchers".
In Brazil, in 1990, there ware about 130 thousand university teachers, 54
thousand with full-salaries, with only 13% of the total holding a doctor
or equivalent degree. The number of administrative employees also grew,
most of them, in the public institutions, with the status and privileges
of civil servants. Academic autonomy, for these new groups, acquired a completely
new meaning. It became, first, the autonomy to chose the university authorities
through direct elections; second, the idea of "gobierno tripartito" remained,
but the alumni were replaced by the employees; third and foremost, but basic
goal of autonomy was to protect the teachers and employees from meritocratic
policies, to assure job stability, equal salaries and regular job promotion.
It would be unfair to say that these groups are not interested in the rationality,
efficiency and quality of university work. They argue that no university
could work without proper salaries and job security for its personnel, and
that these are the basis upon which everything else - good teaching, high
quality research, competent administration - would be built. In recent years,
with the states being forced to reduce their expenditures, salary demands
came to monopolize the full attention and to make it very difficult to raise
other types of issues in countries like Argentina and, to a lesser degree,
in Brazil.
The unions' definition of autonomy, however, is not unchallenged. "Evaluation"
is the new buzzword in Latin American higher education, and it brings back
into the scene two actors which seemed to have disappeared, the academic-researcher
and the alumni. For the former, universities should come under the control
of peer review committees, which should enforce an autonomy based on academic
competence, and not necessarily located in each institution - it is the
academic community, not the universities themselves, which should be the
subject of autonomy. The alumni appear now as the organized liberal professions
- in the field of medicine, law, dentistry, engineering, and many others
- which want to participate in the decisions to create new institutions,
and in the validation of degrees provided by the universities. Autonomy,
for them, should not reside in the universities, but in the professional
associations, which appear as the guardians of the old traditions of professional
autonomy and self-rule. Rationalization, for them, is to have a smaller
number of qualified professionals, which could serve society as well as
possible, according to their own standards, and get the proper compensation
for their work. These redefinitions of "autonomy" share the notion that
the university institution as such is not the legitimate subject of self-rule,
and in that sense they coincide with those in government which cannot see
the universities except as just another section of the public services,
and as such subject to the same rules and controls as everyone else.
I believe this discussion, sketchy as it is, can help to place the question
of "rationalization" in Latin American universities in its context. Far
from being a "technical" or "management" question, the issue of rationalization
is at the core of conflicting groups and their contradictory views about
what universities should be. It is obvious that this discussion has left
out two or three actors which should be at the center of any discussion
of higher education: the families which send their sons to the universities,
the institutions which hire the graduates, and the taxpayer which has to
foot the bill for public education. The reason for their exclusion is that,
so far, they have not been present in the discussions of higher education
in Latin America. This situation is about to change, and, as they enter
the arena, the question of "rationalization" with acquire a completely different
outlook.
Bibliographical note:
This paper was based on several texts produced by the participants in the
Latin American Comparative Project on Higher Education Policies, mostly
by Rollin Kent (Mexico), José Joaquin Brunner (Chile), Jorge Balán (Argentina),
Ricardo Lúcio (Colombia) and Lúcia Klein and Simon Schwartzman (Brazil).
<