
REGIONAL CLEAVAGES AND POLITICAL PARTICIPATION IN BRAZIL
CHAPTER 5
ECONOMIC IMPULSE AND PATRIMONIAL POLITICS
1. Economic development
in the "new" countries
The process of political change described in the preceding chapters had, in
its background, the new relationships between the country and an expanding world
market. One of the most important aspects of the relationship between the marginal
new countries and the central old ones was the pattern of asymmetry, economic
dependency and political interference which came with it.
Less obvious, but certainly as important, was how this kind of external dependency
was reflected in the country's internal structure and political process. Since
there are varying degrees of freedom and alternate possibilities of behavior
in even the tightest bonds of dependency, it is necessary to know which alternatives
are open in a given situation, and the reasons why a given alternative was adopted
instead of another. To take this perspective does not mean, of course, that
the relevance and explanatory power of the political and economic variables
related to external dependency will be neglected; it simply means that the analysis
will be made from the standpoint of the dependent unit, taking the external
system as given, and recovering, as it were, the relative internal autonomy
and possibilities of choice. This chapter is intended as a step in this direction.
It is concerned with changes in the "new countries," given the context
of an expanded international market, and considers some alternative ways in
which these countries may relate to it.
The main economic activity in late eighteenth century Brazil was gold mining.
But its decline was very abrupt, going from an annual average of 14,600 kg. in
the 1741-1760 period to an average of only 1,760 kg. from 1811 to 1820. The Napoleonic
wars and the beginning of free trade with Britain brought a brief prosperity to
the sugar and cotton agriculture, but after 1812-1815, prices declined, and "the
Brazilian political independence occurs at a moment of full world economic recession
and of recession in the Brazilian economy."(1) At the same time, however, coffee was emerging
as the leading product in the country, a situation which would prevail from then
on, as the table below shows.
TABLE 12
BRAZILIAN EXPORTS UP TO 1931 |
Year |
Value in 1,000 |
Value in in 1950 |
% of coffee over total exports |
% of second ranking product |
1821 |
4.30 |
9.40 |
16.30 |
25.30 (sugar) |
1829 |
2.10 |
4.60 |
20.50 |
37.20 |
1830 |
3.30 |
7.30 |
19.80 |
36.70 |
1840-41 |
5.30 |
10.40 |
42.70 |
28.50 |
1850-51 |
8.10 |
21.50 |
48.10 |
23.30 |
1860-61 |
13.20 |
25.00 |
64.70 |
|
1870-71 |
15.40 |
34.00 |
50.30 |
|
1872-73 |
22.30 |
45.00 |
37.60 |
14.70 |
1880-81 |
21.20 |
51.00 |
54.60 |
|
1890 |
26.30 |
75.00 |
50.30 |
|
1900 |
33.10 |
90.00 |
67.70 |
|
1910 |
63.00 |
160.00 |
42.30 |
39.10 (rubber) |
1920 |
82.30 |
67.50 |
49.10 |
6.00 (sugar) |
1929 |
94.80 |
156.00 |
71.00 |
|
1930 |
65.70 |
130.00 |
62.60 |
|
1931 |
49.50 |
122.00 |
68.90 |
|
Source: IBGE, Anuário Estatístico 1940 and 1966. APEC,
Estudos, A Economia Brasileira e Suas Perspectivas, 4 volumes. Oliver
Onody, A Inflação Brasileira 1820-1958 Rio 1960), for the conversion
index to 1950 pounds. |
From the 1860's to the first World War, the volume of Brazilian exports increased
about six fold, due mainly to the expansion of the coffee industry, which had
become, since the second half of the nineteenth century, responsible for 40 to
80 percent of the country's exports.
This economic boom was certainly not an isolated phenomenon,
since it occurred alongside a rapid expansion of the
international market. In the well known "First Wiksel
Lecture" of April, 1959, Ragnar Nurkse presented some
estimates on the expansion of international trade in the
nineteenth century as compared with the contemporary period,
dealing specifically with the pattern of "growth through
trade." From 1850 to 1880, world trade increased) according
to his estimates, by 270 percent; from 1880 to 1913 it increased
170 percent; and the increase for the 1928-58 period was just 57
percent. "The focal center of economic expansion," says
Nurkse, "was initially Great Britain, whose population,
despite heavy migration, trebled in the 19th century while her
national income appears to have increased about ten-fold and the
volume of her imports more than twenty fold."(2)
The countries which benefited more directly from this expansion
were those in the "regions of recent settlement,"
namely Canada, Argentina, Uruguay, South Africa, Australia, New
Zealand and, of course, the United States. According to Nurkse
the share of the "new countries (Canada, Argentina, South
Africa, Australia, New Zealand) in Britain's imports rose from 8
percent in 1857-59 to 18 percent in the 1911-13 period. The share
of British investments, which went to these areas grew from 10
percent in 1870 to 45 percent in 1913.
Brazil also belonged, even if as a minor partner, to this club
of "new" countries which received the impact of British
economic expansion. Brazil had to pay England dearly for the
international recognition of its independence and, with the
economic treaty which Britain imposed upon Brazil in 1827,
"the transfer of the special privileges which England had
enjoyed for centuries in Portuguese commerce was completed, and
the continuation of Great Britain's pre-eminence in the economic
life of its old European ally was assured in Portuguese America,
despite the severance of the colony from the mother country. The
thread of continuity is remarkably clear, running back through
the transition years of 1810-1827 to the Anglo-Portuguese
relations of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries."(3)
Britain was not to remain the main market for Brazilian
agricultural products in the late nineteenth century, but she was
certainly the main supplier of loans and capital investments. As
Manchester puts it, "Great Britain . . . has never made a
question of maintaining its early supremacy in the field of
Brazilian exportations; it is primarily interested in Brazil as a
market for English goods, not as a supplier of raw materials for
home consumption."(4) The
United States became the main market for Brazilian products after
the Civil War and, during the first World War, it supplanted
Great Britain as the principal supplier of capital investments in
the country.
The development of the "new" countries obeyed what
economic historians have called the "staple theory,"
according to which the economy grows on the basis of a leading
export product, which benefits from international comparative
advantages due to the abundance of land and immigrant labor.(5) Open spaces for the production of
new products absorbed by an expanding international market,
availability of foreign capital to finance the transportation and
commercial infra-structure for the new products, and the
immigration of European manpower, all led to an economic impulse
which should have been enough to create, in the long run, a self
sustained and differentiated economy. What has been difficult to
explain is why the staple theory worked so well for some
countries and did not work for others; why some of the
"new" countries of the late nineteenth century's
expansion of international trade are now in the club of high
development, while others lagged behind.
There is a wealth of information and discussions on this
problem, and it would be out of place to introduce this material
here. What is important in this context is to see how this
difficulty in turning the economic impulse of the staple product
into self sustained and diversified economic growth was linked to
the types of institutional and regional differentiation and
cleavages we have been pointing out. We will begin with a close
and well analyzed international comparison, between Argentina and
Australia, and then see how this applies to the Brazilian case.(6)
2.
External impulse and internal differentiation: Argentina and Australia.
Regardless of minor differences in statistical estimates, it
is fairly clear that the rates of development in Argentina and
Australia have been quite similar since the beginning of this
century. According to Hector Dieguez, per capita income in
Argentina rose 99 percent from 1904 to 1960-63, while income in
Australia increased by 113 percent in the same period. What makes
most of the difference, of course, is the starting point. It is
estimated that the per capita income of Australia was already, at
the beginning of the century, 1.75 times that of Argentina.
What concerns Dieguez are less the historical reasons for this
difference than the reasons why the process of industrialization
in the twentieth century did not reduce this difference; in other
words, how did Australia keep and actually increase its relative
advantage through time.
Since the overall relative performance of the Australian
economy was not significantly better than the Argentine, it can
be assumed that both countries behaved at a
"reasonable" level of economic rationality, Australia's
only advantage being the higher starting point. Under closer
examination, however, it becomes clear that Australia had a well
established and purposeful policy of defense and stimulation of
its industrial structure, which Argentina lacked. It is as if the
relative advantage in the international market belonged to
Argentina, and not to Australia; as if Australia needed to work
harder to keep the same levels of economic achievement which
Argentina had with a policy of economic laissez-faire. It also
means, of course, that Argentina could probably have caught up
with Australia in absolute terms if she had had a similar policy
of industrialization.
The reasons for the differences are thus not economic, but
essentially sociological and political, as Hector Dieguez is well
aware:
A mi juicio la solidez político-social alcanzada por
Australia en las primeras dos décadas de este siglo, el
debilitamiento del poder terrateniente, la acción política
organizada del movimiento sindical, y la presencia del
Partido Laborista, fueron elementos importantes para lograr
tempranas políticas de altos salarios y leyes sociales, y lo
que debe destacarse particularmente, para desplazar la
actitud terrateniente reemplazándola por una diferente
actitud general hacia el crecimiento industrial,
circunstancia que se consolida en la década de los veinte.
Durante esta década no se advierte en Argentina una
equivalente actitud hacia el desenvolvimiento industrial.(7)
The historical account presented by Dieguez shows a well- formulated and purposeful
policy of industrialization in Australia, which Argentina certainly lacked. Less
convincing, however, are the links between these policies and the strength of
the trade unions and the Labor Party, which the quotation above implies.
It is difficult to evaluate how much Australia was ahead of
Argentina in terms of political organization and participation in
the first two decades of this century. What is well-known,
nevertheless, is that, in 1912, universal enfranchisement was
established in Argentina by the Sanz Pena Law, leading to high
levels of political participation and the organization of radical
and socialist political parties. Ezequiel Gallo offers evidence
which shows that the radical and socialist groups were fighting,
as in Australia, for higher standards of living, but against
tariffs and other protectionist measure which could help the
industrial development of the country. Higher tariffs meant
higher prices in the short run, and the notion that the interests
of the working and middle classes are fostered when the income of
the industrialist is improved was certainly alien to the popular
ideologies of the time. As Gallo puts it,
The Socialist party (in Argentina) resolutely opposed two
kinds of measures: legislation tending towards a devaluation
of the Argentinian peso and any attempt to raise the tariff
barriers. Both measures would have had an adverse effect on
the standard of living of the workers (in the case of the
tariffs, it must be remembered that despite import
substitution, a significant proportion of the consumer goods
purchased by the workers was still imported)(8)
Which means that the little industrial development Argentina had was not due to
the political strength of these "modern" social sectors, but was achieved
almost in spite of them.
3. A model of change
The model implicit in Gallo's discussion can be expressed in
the graph below:
The formulation of the explanatory model for Brazil is usually attributed to Celso
Furtado, and the criticism to which it has been subject follows a pattern similar
to the debate on Argentine development, described above.(9)
First, regarding the negative link between industry and
agriculture, there is a widespread notion that a natural
hostility exists between these two sectors, which is not
supported empirically. The theory works in terms of comparative
costs, according to which it would be cheaper and more convenient
to import manufactured products than to produce them at home,
when foreign currency is available and industrial tradition is
lacking. The development of a national industry would require
tariff barriers, tolerance for higher costs and low quality, and
other protective measures which the agriculturists would not be
interested in supporting. Besides, the establishment of
protective tariffs always brings the risk of reciprocity, and the
closing of the foreign market to export products.
Although correct in its more general terms, this theory does
not cover all the facts. An active export economy does not
exclude, as it did not in São Paulo, a series of related and
unrelated industrial and urban activities. Directly related to it
are items of transport, processing and commercial organization.
The money economy, which was stimulated by wages paid by the
coffee plantations, created a demand for products which could not
easily be imported from abroad:
Along with bricks, almost every kind of construction
material was domestically produced by 1920: tiles, cement,
nails, ceramic pipes, lumber, arid even plate glass and
plumbing fixtures. Other obvious examples are beer and soft
drinks (and bottles to put them in), shoes, boilers, coarse
textiles, furniture, stonework, flour, pots and pans, and
hats(10)
A third source of manufacturing development was the decision of the merchants
and importers to finance the national production or finishing of goods, rather
than bring them in from abroad. This combination of export, import and manufacturing
interests is quite far from the image of an urban, entrepreneur capitalism struggling
against traditional agricultural sectors. The fact is that an active and dynamic
export agriculture can hardly be considered "traditional" on closer
examination, as we shall see further on. The positive correlation between an export
economy and industrialization is explicitly stated by Ezequiel Gallo:
The strategic variable in the process of
industrialization undergone by these regions has been the
steady expansion of demand, which in turn resulted from the
increase in incomes generated by the successful performance
of the export sector.(11)
High tariffs and external crises are usually seen together as factors which give
strength to the development of national manufacture. The two World Wars and the
1929 world crisis are seen as circumstances which impaired the flow of international
trade, reduced the availability of foreign currency and foreign products, and
freed the national industry from foreign competition. The fact, however, seems
to have been that world crises had a depressing effect on the economy as a whole,
including the industrial sector.(12) It
is true that, during the Second World War, Brazil had a limited participation
in the western war effort, and this led, for instance, to the creation of the
first steel plant in the country, Volta Redonda, the first motor engine plant,
the Fábrica Nacional de Motores, etc. In his comparison between Argentina and
Australia) Hector Dieguez notices that Australia had to produce supplies for the
troops engaged in the First World War; moreover, it was the main Allied base in
the Pacific after 1942, having to make a war effort similar to Great Britain's.(13) What these examples show is not that the wars
had a positive effect on the process of industrialization, but that they could
lead to political and psychological situations in which a conscious and purposeful
effort of economic organization and production could be made possible. In other
words, the market mechanisms created by external crises tend to be mostly
negative, but the political and psychological effects can have the opposite
result.
This question of market vs. political mechanisms is very
important when it comes to the issue of protective tariffs. The
idea of complementary interests between the export and
manufacturing sectors is based on a similarity of interests and
activities, which occur on a day-to-day basis. In other words,
the final outcome is an aggregate of a large number of individual
decisions. The idea of a conflict of interests, however, would
probably need a change from the economic to the political level:
that is, a clear and conscious political effort would be
necessary to keep the government from raising the tariffs. In
this scenario, the agriculturists would organize themselves as a
lobby in the fight for low tariffs, while the industrialists
would be organized and lobbying for them.
As it happened, this scenario did not exist. When tariffs were
established, the objective was not to protect industry, but to
bring in resources for the government. Dean is very clear on
this:
The central government of the Republic spent more money
than had the Empire; the tariff continued to be, however, the
only significant source of revenue that the planters would
grant. The available alternatives would obviously be more
painful to them: a tax on land or a tax on incomes or profit.
Therefore, the federal government, whose expenses had grown
from 434,000 contos ($87,000,000) to 1,227,000 contos
($257,000,000) between 1900 and 1920, relied on customs
duties to provide about 70 percent of its income. Though such
a tariff would necessarily be protective in effect, its
intent was merely fiscal.(14)
The political significance of this statement is very high. Tariffs were accepted
by the agriculturists, as Dean puts it, faute de mieux; and they were not
meant to protect the industry. What they were meant for, of course, was to finance
an ever-growing governmental bureaucracy, which increased three-fold in the period
of maximum political decentralization of the country's history. The expanding
export economy supported the State and, at the same time, accepted tariff protection
for an industry which she did not particularly mean to support. The tariff system
in Brazil from 1900 to 1934 was casuistic, and specific tariff protections could
be obtained through particularistic means and private lobbying. Hence, Dean concludes
that "the particularism of the industrialists' claims to government favors
led to a dependence upon the existing political structure.(15)
In short, if we consider the weight of the three sectors - the central government,
the agriculturists, and the industrialists - it becomes clear that the first certainly
had the political control of the situation; the industrialists were the weakest
group. The agriculturists had some power to decide where the government could
draw their resources, but they were unable to curtail the continuous growth of
the patrimonialist governmental bureaucracy.
Which brings us to another element of the model, the
"modern" (socialist, middle class, trade union)
sectors. Sociological common sense tends to link these modern,
"leftist" social groups to the progressive social
sector, the industrialists, and infer an opposition of interests
between these modern and progressive sectors, on the one hand,
and the agricultural sectors, on the other. It is curious how the
classic opposition and hatred between workers and bourgeois seems
to disappear in the context of underdevelopment, under the aegis
of common progressivism and modern outlook.
Empirical evidence, however, does not support what ideologies
of development would expect. Brazilian industrialists, according
to Dean, did not develop a well formulated policy of industrial
development, and were not in the least concerned with national
progress as such. They depended on particularist favors from the
government; they had to give continuous demonstrations of loyalty
and support, and "in effect they had aligned themselves not
with the reformist middle class but with the landowners, and
invariably they provided unquestioning political support.
Industrialism, with its potential for social transformation, was
thwarted in effect by a regressive and opportunist alliance with
the class least likely to favor that transformation."(16)
If the industrialists did not like the "progressive"
groups, the reciprocal was certainly true. Early industrialism in
Brazil was similar in its ruthlessness and exploitation of labor
to its British counterpart in the preceding century, and strikes
and other forms of class conflicts in Brazil occurred with
intensity in the first decades of the century. The country's
middle class, very often dependent on the governmental
bureaucracy or on the merchant groups, had a clear preference for
foreign products, and joined other social sectors in the secular
complaint on the "artificiality" of the national
industry.
The conflict of interests between industrialists and
importers, which is to be expected when the national industry
starts to claim protection against foreign products, is thus
enlarged with an alliance between importers and consumers from
the "middle" and low sectors. Here, again, the analysis
of Brazil coincides with what Gallo finds in Argentina. He shows
that, in spite of an objective interest of the export groups in
low tariffs, a relative stabilization of tariff levels in
Argentina occurred only during the 1913-25 period, which
coincides with the arrival of the Radical Party to the
government:
It is important to realize that from 1916 until 1930,
political power passed to the party generally identified with
the "rising middle classes." The "growing
rigidity" of the tariff policy thus coincided with the
time when political power was slipping out of the hands of
the traditional ruling classes. And what is more, it was
precisely the representatives in Congress of the new popular
parties, radicals arid socialists, who opposed most actively
any attempt to raise tariff barriers.(17)
If we look back at the reasons offered by Hector Dieguez for the relative backwardness
of Argentina as compared to Australia, it is possible to see that we have come
full circle. There is a striking contradiction between Gallo and Dieguez, even
though the political ingredients considered important by Dieguez - a strong labor
movement, an organized working-class party, positively related with a favorable
attitude towards industrial development - seem to have worked in Australia. What
Gallo seems to imply, however, is that Argentina did not develop an explicit policy
of industrialization, not because of the lack of some of these elements, but exactly
because of their existence.
What this analysis shows is that there are two elements which
are lacking in the model we have been discussing; or at least,
they are not taken systematically into consideration. The first
is the role and characteristics of the State in which the
external impulse is implanted. The second is an explicit
consideration of the transition between market mechanisms
expressing the aggregate interplay of individual interests and
the explicit formulation of policy orientations by organized
social groups.
The two elements are closely linked to each other. There is an
important difference between a new nation such as Australia,
which was created as an outgrowth of the expanding British
economy, and "new nations' such as Brazil or Argentina,
where the external economic impulse was established within a
pre-existing context of political patrimonialism and dependence
on the productive activities of the patrimonial state. In these
"old new nations," politics never fell into the hands
of the new economic groups, even when the old power sectors had
to change their style and open the political system to new forms
of participation. In Argentina, in spite of massive international
im- migration, political power remained basically in the hands of
the old traditional elite, who owned large-scale cattle-raising
properties and were skilled in controlling the state machinery. (18). In Brazil, the number of
immigrants was smaller, and they went mostly to São Paulo, an
area which had been marginal to the main- stream of Brazilian
society since the Emboabas War until the coffee rush in the late
nineteenth century. This geographical division added an element
of regionalism to the political and economic differences between
São Paulo and the center of Brazilian political life in Rio,
which is fundamental for an explanation of what was to happen in
the country's political life throughout most of the following
decades.
4. The political
economy of coffee expansion
The Brazilian coffee economy began its expansion in the mid
nineteenth century, and followed a pattern of expanding frontier
due to a combination of increasing production and progressive
exhaustion of the land. In 1859, almost 80 percent of the
Brazilian coffee production came from the state of Rio de
Janeiro, 12.1 percent from São Paulo, and 7.8 percent from Minas
Gerais. In 1902, São Paulo concentrated 65.2 percent of the
production, Minas 22.8 percent, and Rio de Janeiro only 9.7
percent.(19)
The reasons for this dramatic geographic shift in fifty years
were related to the availability of virgin lands, but they were
also a function of the possibilities of securing a labor supply
and financial support. When, after 1897, the production of coffee
surpassed the demands of the world market and a crisis of
overproduction was declared, the maintenance of high levels of
production and income started to depend on an active policy of
price "valorization" through control of supply(20). To get labor and capital
first, and then influence the conditions of the world market were
tasks which demanded active and coordinated efforts by the coffee
growers. This was not always possible, and on the whole, the
Paulista coffee growers were much more successful than the
Mineiros or Fluminenses (from the State of Rio de Janeiro). It
was true that the quality of the soil in São Paulo was
exceptionally favorable to the expansion of production which took
place in that state. But it is not evident that the soil in Minas
Gerais was that much worse, or that the differences in the
quality of land were so much more important than the political
and sociological characteristics of the areas in which coffee was
planted.(21)
The best source on the social nature of the early coffee
plantations in Brazil is certainly Stanley J. Stein's Vassouras.(22) A small settlement along the
route which linked Rio de Janeiro with the gold areas of Minas
Gerais, Vassouras and the valley of the Parahyba River became a
central area of coffee production in the expansion which took
place between 1830 and 1850, raising the volume of Rio's exports
from about two million to more than ten million
"arrobas" (one "arroba" equals 31.7 pounds)
during the period. Decadence came to Vassouras almost as quickly
as wealth and progress had a few decades before, and Stein
provides a detailed and relevant description of what happened.
A substantial part of the decadence is explained by the
worn-out soil, aging coffee trees, dwindling virgin forest and
reserves and erosion, all consequences of predatory plantation
techniques used in a situation where land was the cheapest and
most abundant of productive factors. Celso Furtado has argued
that this was the most rational thing to do, since the
deterioration of land was the most rational thing to do, since
the deterioration of land was compensated by the amount of wealth
created by the plantation. This type of reasoning makes sense
from the standpoint of the country's economy as a whole, since
the land seemed to be endless and the country's production did
not cease growing.(23) However,
for the individual planter in Vassouras, or, for that matter, for
the county as a whole, economic and social decadence was hard and
proved impossible to overcome. They were unable to secure a fresh
labor force to substitute the aging and expensive slaves, nor did
they have credit to finance their crops, to substitute the old
coffee trees, or to try more rational and less predatory
plantation techniques.
Coffee plantation needs credit, since it takes four years of
initial investment for newly planted trees to bear fruit. The
initial source of credit were the planter's factors in Rio, who
took care of the commercialization of the product and retained
the loans, their interests and their profits. When decadence
came, the dependence of the planters on these factors increased,
and in the 1850's the Brazilian central bank, the Banco do
Brasil, started to finance directly the troubled coffee planters.
The planter seemed to rely on his political influence, nobility
titles, and personal ties to avoid the pressure of his official
creditor. Stein refers to several mechanisms through which the
planters could keep "their indifference toward fulfilling
signed obligations requiring prompt repayment of capital and
interest."(24) And a
contemporary observer is quoted as saying that "nowhere in
all the world - at least not in Netherlands India - are
agriculturists granted so many legal securities to enable them to
cultivate their lands in peace, as in Brazil"(25) Financial support for the
planters was given for a while against all the logic of
economics:
The pump priming occurred despite temporarily declining
overseas coffee markets, the competition of cheaper coffee
grown in São Paulo's expanding groves outside the Parahyba
Valley, and lower production in the worn-out debtor areas of
the province (26)
This growing indebtedness to and dependence on the government in Rio did not give
the planter freedom of action to solve the labor problem, which was crucial.(27)
After 1850, the African slave traffic came to an end, and from
then until the end of the slave system, in 1888, labor
substitution became very difficult. The price of slaves almost
doubled from 1852-54 and grew exponentially until around 1880,
when the slave system began to crumble.(28)
In spite of substantial internal slave traffic, the slave labor
force grew older, the man-to-woman rate became more even, and the
slave population became more of a liability than an asset:
This crucial segment of the plantation working force, the
fifteen to forty year olds, dropped from a high of 62 percent
of the total labor force in 1830-1849 to 51 percent in the
succeeding decade, and finally to 35 percent in the last
eight years of slavery.(29)
It is difficult to explain the inability of the coffee- growers in the Rio area
to overcome the labor problem. One common explanation refers to the difficulties
of bringing together slave and free labor, since it could mean an unbearable lowering
of the free laborer to the slave's condition. Manual labor would be equated with
slave labor, and no free man would ever accept it willingly.
For this psychological explanation to be valid, however, the
social, economic and racial boundaries between slaves and low-
class freemen should have been much sharper than was the case in
nineteenth century Brazil.(30) As
it was, other systems of labor had been tried in the Vassouras
area before the end of the slavery system, without success. Share
tenancy, sharecropping and salaried labor were tried with
different degrees of failure, and after the abolition of slavery
the "organization of remaining fazenda coffee
production crystallized in the form of share-cropping or parceria,
supplemented by jobbing."(31)
The share system implied that the proprietor did not have to
care too much for the daily activities of his tenancy, while the
freedmen could have a resemblance of independence and a small
property. Here, as elsewhere, a pattern of exchange between
economic decadence and patrimonial dependence can be observed.
All influential planters of Vassouras held nobility titles in the
Brazilian Empire, and the percentage of coffee barons among all
title holders in the Empire rose from 21 to 26 percent from 1840
to 1870. Titles were given, according to Stein, for their
"financial contributions in the Paraguayan War, or their
local or national prominence in supporting the Imperial regime,
or their philanthropic acts."(32)
This rather generous distribution of (non-hereditary) nobility
titles is an indication of the importance the planters gave to
their links with the seat of the imperial government. This link
was not only a matter of prestige but, as we have seen, was
closely related to the sources of financing and economic support,
which they could find only in Rio de Janeiro.
Share-cropping allowed for a combination of export and subsistence agriculture,
since the tenant could usually cultivate a piece of land for his own consumption.
This feature, combined with the political influence of the planter, increased
the ability of the more traditional coffee plantations to survive the impact of
economic storms in the short run, but reduced their ability to influence the process
in the long run.
The difference between what occurred in Rio de Janeiro and Minas Gerais, on one
hand, and São Paulo on the other, is striking. In São Paulo, the production of
coffee was boosted by an active policy of bringing immigrants from Europe and
placing them in a system of very intensive and capitalist-like exploitation of
labor. There are two general patterns of immigration to Brazil, one known as "colonization"
and the other "immigration" as such. The first tended to be directed
and induced by the central government, and was an attempt to create an independent,
productive, European-like peasantry in the country. The other, promoted more directly
by planters in São Paulo, and later by the government in that state, was concerned
specifically with obtaining manpower for the coffee plantations.(33)
The "'colonization" pattern was relatively successful in the southern
states of Rio Grande and Santa Catarina, where large German colonies were established.(34)
Immigration, however, was dominant, and São Paulo was, increasingly, the promoter
and area of destination of this flux, as the table below shows.(35)
TABLE 13
IMMIGRATION TO BRAZIL AND SÃO PAULO, 1884 - 1888 |
Year |
Number of immigrants |
Percent of Italians |
Percent going to São Paulo |
Percent of expenses of the State of
São Paulo with immigration in relation to expenses of the Imperial Government
|
1884 |
24,800 |
41 |
20 |
38 |
1885 |
35,440 |
61 |
18 |
35 |
1886 |
33,486 |
61 |
28 |
83 |
1887 |
55,963 |
72 |
57 |
119 |
1888 |
133,253 |
78 |
69 |
75 |
Source: Calculated from J. Fernando Carneiro, Imigração
e Colonização no Brasil (Rio de Janeiro, Universidade do Brasil, Faculdade
Nacional de Filosofia, Cadeira de Geografia do Brasil, 1950), p. 24. |
After 1889, when the Republican period
began, the pattern of federal and state expenditures was erratic,
indicating that a division of attributions between the two levels
of government was still to be established. From 1889 to 1891, the
federal government seemed to take on the burden of immigration
expenses; after that, the contribution of the state of São Paulo
was not constant, but always significantly high. From 1902 to
1906, the central government substantially reduced its
participation in the financing of immigration, leaving it almost
entirely to São Paulo. After 1906, the problem of manpower was
practically overcome in São Paulo. The immigration pattern
changed, the Italians gave way to the Portuguese and the
Spaniards, and the problem which afflicted the coffee planters
was no longer labor, but prices in the international market.
TABLE 14
EXPENSES OF THE CENTRAL GOVERNMENT AND SÃO PAULO ON IMMIGRATION, RELATIVE
FIGURES, 1884-1906* |
Year |
a. Expenses of the State of São Paulo
(1889=100) |
b. Expenses of the Federal Government
(1889=100) |
a/b (absolute values) |
a+b (1889=100) |
number of immigrants who entered the
country (per 1,000) |
1884 |
235 |
15.0 |
38.3 |
21 |
25 |
1885 |
230 |
16.0 |
35.2 |
21 |
35 |
1886 |
712 |
21.0 |
82.7 |
38 |
33 |
1887 |
2,014 |
42.0 |
118.9 |
90 |
56 |
1888 |
1,819 |
60.0 |
75.1 |
103 |
133 |
1889 |
100 |
100.0 |
2.5 |
100 |
65 |
1890 |
474 |
46.0 |
25.6 |
57 |
107 |
1891 |
320 |
169.0 |
3.0 |
170 |
216 |
1892 |
437 |
50.0 |
21.8 |
11 |
86 |
1893 |
993 |
41.0 |
59.9 |
24 |
134 |
1894 |
295 |
14.0 |
51.8 |
21 |
60 |
1895 |
1,582 |
45.0 |
88.7 |
82 |
167 |
1896 |
785 |
76.0 |
25.8 |
93 |
158 |
1897 |
1,002 |
4.0 |
617.3 |
28 |
146 |
1898 |
463 |
7.0 |
202.7 |
17 |
78 |
1899 |
383 |
1.1 |
889.8 |
10 |
53 |
1900 |
245 |
10.0 |
59.4 |
16 |
37 |
1901 |
1,196 |
28.0 |
104.8 |
29 |
83 |
1902 |
556 |
0.9 |
1,506.5 |
14 |
50 |
1903 |
69 |
0.9 |
183.7 |
3 |
32 |
1904 |
194 |
1.4 |
354.8 |
6 |
44 |
1905 |
1,149 |
1.8 |
1,635.1 |
30 |
68 |
1906 |
750 |
1.9 |
1,248.3 |
25 |
72 |
Source: Calculated from J. Fernando Carneiro, Imigração e
Colonização no Brasil (Rio de Janeiro, 1950), pp. 24-28.
*Values from 1889 on are deflated by the exchange rate with the British
pound. |
A systematic effort to control the supply and influence the prices of coffee in
the international market started precisely in 1906, with the Taubaté agreement,
signed between the government of the states of São Paulo, Minas Gerais and Rio
de Janeiro. A previous attempt to control the supply had been tried before by
the government of São Paulo when, in 1902, it forbade the planting of new coffee
trees for five years.(36) It is well-known that the initiative behind
the Taubaté agreement and subsequent measures of price control came from the Paulista
coffee producers; Delfim Netto links this entrepreneurship with the differences
in the labor systems of the two leading states, Minas and São Paulo. The labor
system in São Paulo was of a contractual and monetary kind (colonato),
while in the rest of the country, and especially in Minas Gerais, labor relations
were based on share-cropping (parceria). The difference between these two
systems appeared when the prices in the international market fell at the beginning
of the twentieth century. The coffee entrepreneur in São Paulo was much more vulnerable
to price fluctuations than his counterpart working in the parceria system,
and this is why, according to Delfim Netto, "it was not surprising that the
pressure towards (national) state intervention (in the coffee industry) began
in São Paulo."(37)
The Republican system of 1889-1930 started thus with
considerable decentralization of power, and with a leading state
taking into its own hands the management of its interests in the
field of labor supply, control of production, and so on. In the
rest of the country, however, other patterns of social and
political participation guaranteed that this economic leader-
ship would not go too far in political terms.
5. The pattern of patrimonial
dependence.
The foregoing discussion suggests a pattern of dependency
already implied in the analysis of the effects of economic
decadence in chapter three. The expression "patrimonial
dependence" may be useful to convey the meaning of the type
of symbiosis this pattern implies.
Patrimonial rule, as defined earlier, is a type of traditional
domination based on an extension of the ruler's household. The
existence of patrimonial domination depends on the control of
society's production process by the ruler and his entourage.
Hence, there is a link between the Weberian concept of
patrimonialism and Marx s notion of "Asiatism," which
refers to a pre-capitalist type of society in which private
property and isolated fiefs are not present. Patrimonial
domination exists, in its classic manifestation, in the hydraulic
societies studied by Wittfogel; it also exists in states
specializing either in military conquest or in mercantilist trade
and colonial exploitation.
The important question is how patrimonial domination survives when its hold over
the economic productive or extractive systems starts to dwindle. The history of
Portugal, as mentioned before, shows a consistent pattern of obtaining support
for political dominance at the expense of economic concessions to England.
In his classic work on the British Preeminence in Brazil, Alan C. Manchester
gives abundant historical evidence on how this process of exchange remained in
Brazil, after its independence from Portugal in 1822. Among the treaties signed
between the Portuguese government exiled in Brazil in 1810 and England, there
is one that granted privileges of all kinds to British products and British citizens
in Portuguese territory; another dealt with political questions, guaranteed a
perpetual union between the two countries, included a British pledge "never
to recognize as sovereign of Portugal any prince who was not the legitimate heir
of the house of Bragança," and added other political reassurances.(38)
The same pattern of exchange of economic power for political privilege was apparent
in Argentina where, according to the analysis of Gallo and Cortes Conde, a pattern
of growth "towards the outside", with intensive use of foreign capital,
kept the more traditional political groups relatively protected.
The overall pattern of Portuguese colonization seems to have
been one of progressive political centralization, which occurred
simultaneously with and was intensified by steady economic
decadence in several levels and areas. We have seen how the
arrangement with Flemish interests in the sugar economy seems to
have given the bulk of economic profit to the Dutch, in exchange
for Portuguese sovereignty over Brazilian territory. After its
independence from Spain, Portugal increased its dependence on
England, and the treaties between the two countries conceded
economic privileges to England in exchange for political
commitments and guarantees. The climax of this dependent
relationship was the treaty of Methuen between England and
Portugal in 1703. With this treaty, Portugal was able to
guarantee its control over the Amazon against France and over the
Colônia de Sacramento against Spain, as well as the access of
Portuguese wine to the English market. The price was, according
to Furtado, the renunciation of the development of a Portuguese
industry, and the transference to England of the dynamic impulse
created by the gold production in Brazil.(39)
In Minas Gerais, strict fiscal controls were established over
the mining areas, and control tightened as the availability of
gold declined.(40) In the South,
in spite of the modest success of the dried beef and wheat
economies, military activities in behalf of the politics of
Lisbon and Rio never lost their importance. And Rio, of course,
became the administrative capital of the country in 1763, during
the gold rush, thereafter living off the benefits of being the
seat of the central administration and the Crown. Political
dependence due to colonial status, economic subjugation to
Portugal and especially England, and bureaucratic centralization
for the exploitation of resources produced by an overall decadent
economy - all of these traits comprise the broad setting with
which Brazil enters the nineteenth century. During most of the
new century, Brazil made mediocre progress, and, as the economy
stagnated, the process of political centralization and control
grew stronger.(41)
Historical studies will hopefully document the more specific
relationships between economic decay and political
centralization. Celso Furtado has suggested that the sugar
economy in the Northeast was able to resist the fall of sugar
prices by reverting to a type of self-sufficient activity, which
comes closer than anything else to a Brazilian version of feudal
patrimonialism.(42) If this was
so, what happened to the administrative and commercial activities
related to this retracting economy? Historians have yet to answer
this question.(43) But what most
likely happened is that as the mere dynamic commercial sectors
disappeared or moved out, the governmental administration
retreated into a kind of bureaucratic ritualism, to which the
highly centralized and formalized Portuguese administrative
structure was so conducive.
In general terms, the pattern of Portuguese colonization seems
to have been composed of two typical movements. First, the
administration gave all kinds of facilities to private
initiative, and this led both to economic prosperity and to the
dispersion of power. During a second stage, the administration
increased its grip through a series of centralizing restrictions,
leading to unavoidable conflicts with private entrepreneurs. This
centralization and increase in control was a reaction to
reductions of revenue; this seems to have happened in the sugar
economy, and was certainly the case with the decadence of mining
in the late eighteenth century. It happened again in the early
nineteenth century during the Portuguese Courts' attempts to
restore Brazil to its colonial status.(44)
This pattern of external dependence, which was to continue
throughout this century, thus meant not only that national
resources and wealth were siphoned abroad, which, in a way, is
trivial; but also that, in this process, the patrimonial state
was able to survive and thwart the chances of independent
political organization and manifestation of national groups,
which had a productive basis of their own, whether as
industrialists, capitalists, or workers. Confronted with a
dominant political sector, which had the support of strong
foreign economic interests, national political groups could
pressure, beg, and lobby for special favors and concessions from
those in political power; but they could never aspire to conquer
it and direct it towards their own purposes. The consequence was
the lack of "political will and purpose," which
Argentine economists and historians saw only in Australia, and
which could eventually change a relatively deprived situation
into a determined policy of industrialization and development.
Only the State itself would be able, under given conditions, to
try this shift, independently and sometimes at the expense of the
political parties and social sectors of the country. This
"lack of political will and purpose" is not a cultural
or psychological trait, of course, but the outcome of a situation
of internal dependence which replicates, as it were, an external
dependence on the capitalist centers of the world economy. It is
from this type of dependence that emerges the style of political
participation which is being referred to as
"co-optation," and which will later be considered again
in more detail.
Notes
1. Virgílio Noya Pinto (1969), p. 132.
The data above are from the same source.
2. Ragnar Nurkse (1968), p. 87.
3. Alan K. Manchester (1933), p. 210.
4. Alan K. Manchester (1933), p. 334.
5. On the "staple theory," see
Richard Caves (1965), and M. Watkins (1963).
6. Some of the comparative studies on this
topic are Hector L. Dieguez (1968); Arthur Smithies (1965); and
A. Ferrer and E. L. Wheelwright (n. d.).
7. Hector Dieguez (1968), pp. 16-17.
8. Ezequiel Gallo (1970), pp. 57-58.
9. Celso Furtado (1959). For a historical
re-interpretation of the theory, see Warren Dean (1969)
especially chapters vi and x; Warner Baer and Aníbal Villela
(1972); Nathaniel H. Leff (1969); and several other sources
mentioned in the Baer and Villela article.
10. Dean (1969), p. 10.
11. Gallo (1970), p. 53.
12. Warren Dean (1969), chapter VI.
Summing up a careful analysis of the data available, Dean states
that "World War I considerably increased the demand for
domestic manufactured goods but made it almost impossible to
enlarge the productive plant to meet the demand. The fortunes
that were made during the war grew out of new lines of exports,
twenty-four hour-a-day production, or out of mergers and
reorganizations. New plants and new lines of manufactures were
not significant. It might be asked if the industrialization of
São Paulo would not have proceeded faster had there been no
war," (1969), p. 104.
13. G. Long (1947), quoted by Hector
Dieguez (1968), p. 20.
14. Dean (1969), p. 71. The same
situation of tariffs established with fiscal purposes but
providing protective effects appears much earlier, according to
studies by Gilberto Paim, which finds it in relation to Brazil's
nineteenth century industrialization. Cf. G. Paim (1957), p. 30.
15. Dean (1969), p. 72.
16. Dean (1969), pp. 72-73.
17. Gallo (1970), p. 57. The sources used
by Gallo are Carlos F. Diaz Alejandro (1967) and Oscar Cornblit
(1967).
18. Summing up a study on the formation
of contemporary Argentina, Roberto Cortes Conde and Ezequiel
Gallo say that, in spite of being "bastante secularizado y
fuera muy dinámico," the political leadership of the
country was already too well established in power to yield its
place to the emerging immigrant groups: "Por el escaso poder
económico y la relativa marginalidad de los grupos que podían
haber asumido la dirección de una política industrialista,
extranjeros en su mayoría, dentro de una sociedad ya
estructurada y con la presencia de un grupo dirigente
tradicional, resulta compreensible la dificultad de hacer
acceptable una nueva política para la mayoría de la poblacion.
Esto diferencia a la Argentina de la mayor parte de las regiones
de nuevo poblamiento, donde casi todos eran recien llegados y se
encontraban en condiciones similares." The only possible
growth was "hacia afuera," outwards, in such a way that
well established power situations would not be threatened. Cf. R.
Cortes Conde and Ezequiel Gallo (1967).
19. Cf. Elisa Maria Pereira Reis (1972),
p. 6.
20. For an account and evaluation of the
Brazilian policy of sustaining the coffee prices, see Antonio
Delfim Netto (1959).
21. An official publication of the State
of Minas Gerais estimated that, in 1929, there was still about
11,000,000 hectares of virgin land suitable for coffee
plantations, and that with only half of that land it would be
possible to plant more than 5,000,000,000 coffee trees, or about
five times what São Paulo had at that time. Estado de Minas
Gerais (1929).
22. Stanley J. Stein (1957).
23. Celso Furtado (1968). Predatory use
of land was rational, for him, not only from the individual
capitalist's point of view but also from society's point of view
as a whole: "If the exhaustible reserve (of soils) is
utilized so as to start a process of development, not only will
the present generation be benefited but also those to come, which
will be inheriting that mineral deposit in the form of
reproductive capital." Furtado (1968), p. 179
24. Stein (1957), p. 241.
25. Stein (1957), p. 242.
26. Stein (1957), p. 244.
27. Cf. C. Furtado (1968), chapters xxi
to xxiv, for an analysis of the problems of manpower in Brazil
during this period.
28. Stein (1957), pp. 65 and 229.
29. Stein (1957), p. 78.
30. Cf. Herbert S. Klein (1969). A
pattern of intensive racial miscegenation is observed, giving
rise to a substantial freed population. The article concludes
saying that the fact that so many freedmen were being manumitted
at such a constant and rapid rate in the nineteenth century,
during the greatest expansion of the plantation economy, suggests
the fundamental acceptance by white Brazilians of the possibility
of a functioning interracial free labor society well before the
institution of slavery itself was seriously challenged. Klein
(1969), p. 52.
31. Stein (1957), p. 271.
32. Stein (1957), p. 122.
33. An overview of the immigration
patterns in Brazil is given by Manuel Dieguez Jr. (1964). A basic
reference is Artur Hehl Neiva (1945). Figures on immigration from
1819 to 1947 broken down by year and country of origin can be
found in Artur Hehl Neiva and J. Fernando Carneiro (1950), and in
J. Fernando Carneiro (1950).
34. For an analysis of the
"colonization" pattern, mostly in southern Brazil, see
R. Paula Lopes (1936).
35. For a detailed description of the
migratory flow and types of settlement in São Paulo, see Salvío
de Almeida Azevedo (1941).
36. Elisa Maria Pereira Reis (1972), p.
8.
37. Antonio Delfim Netto (1959), pp 43-44. The comparison
between the '"colonato"' and the "parceria" systems is based
on Augusto Ramos (1934).
38. Manchester (1933), p. 91.
39. Cf. Celso Furtado (1959), p. 47. For the relationships
between Brazil and England, see Alan K. Manchester (1933), as well as the summary
given by Furtado in Chapter vii of his book.
40. R. Faoro (1958) for a description of this process.
41. The image of the second half of the eighteenth century
as one of continuous decadence is not quite correct. There is a period of economic
resurgence at the end of the century, due mainly to new crops and a recuperation
of the sugar prices. This development is analyzed by Dauril Alden for the Viceroyalty
of Rio, and he sums up by saying that "the record of the attempts of Viceroy
Lavradio and his successor to diversify the economy of the lands under their jurisdiction
was a mixed one. There were some modest successes, such as indigo, rice, and wheat
growing, and there were some notable disappointments, particularly cochineal,
hemp and tobacco." Dauril Alden (1968), p. 381.
42. Followíng the analysis of the economic decline in the
sugar area, Furtado says that ít led to a sharper reversion to forms of subsistence
economy, with atrophy in the division of labor, reduction in productivity, dissolution
of the system into increasingly smaller productive units, extinction of the more
complex forms of social intercourse, and substitution of general law by local
custom. Furtado (1968), p. 77.
43. This analysis is intended, but not quite achieved, in
Antonio de Barros Castro (1971).
44. A major event in Brazilian history is the arrival of the
whole Portuguese court to Rio de Janeiro in 1808, flying from the French invaders
under British protection. A detailed description of this trip is given by Alan
K. Manchester (1969). The political independence of Brazil from Portugal is linked
to the attempts of the Portuguese parliament, the "Cortes," to recall
the royal family from Brazil and reinstate the colonial status which had existed
prior to 1808. See a summary of these events in E. B. Burns (1970), pp. 105-116.